Actualités

Partager sur :

What history tells you about post pandemic booms

07 mai 2021 Divers
Vue 235 fois

En ce moment , de nombreux articles  cherchent à prévoir comment sera le "monde d'après" . Très souvent on se focalise sur l'économie mais les analyses des pandémies de l'histoire, de la peste noire à Ebola ,montrent  un panel  de conséquences plus large.

Parmi ces textes, essentiellement dans la presse anglophone, celui de "The Economist" semble le plus documenté et le mieux construit.

 
Il dégage 3  leçons  principales:
 
1) Les inégalités sociales sont moins acceptées et des troubles sociaux peuvent éclater après les crises sanitaires.The Economist prend l'exemple de Gavroche sur les barricades après l'épidémie de choléra de 1830 . On pourrait rajouter les crise en Afrique de l'Ouest après les épidémies d'Ebola.  Cette fois les dirigeants auront peut être désamorcé ce volet en lançant de gigantesques plans de relance qui devraient sauver les emplois .

2) Durant les crises les bas de laine gonflent mais ils se vident doucement lors du retour à la normale. Ce n'est pas la grande teuf à la fin de la pandémie! Seule une partie des excédents d'épargne sont consommés...  peut être seulement 20%.
 
3) Après les crises , on prend plus de risque pour explorer des nouveaux champs :
Certains ont cherché de nouveaux territoires:   Christophe Colomb , Magellan, Vasco de Gama ont découvert de nouvelles terres après la peste noire. Mais c'est surtout la mise en oeuvre de nouvelles avancées technologiques qui domine :  l'imprimerie de Guthenberg après la peste ,révolution industrielle après le choléra, Robotisation  après le SRAS . Nous pouvons nous attendre à une accélération de la digitalisation après la Covid 19, elle a déjà commencé.
 
Voici ,ci dessous ,un résumé de l'article de "The Economist".
In English of course because one day you got the B2 level and you need to refresh it.
May the force be with you!Google Trad vous aidera!
 
Jean Luc Taupiac

 

 What history tells you about post pandemic booms

People spend more, take more risks—and demand more of politicians | Finance & economics

Past disasters offer a guide to what will happen once life gets back to normal. Many countries are in for unusually fast economic growth

People spend more, take more risks—and demand more of politicians | Finance & economics

THE CHOLERA pandemic of the early 1830s hit France hard. It wiped out nearly 3% of Parisians in a month, and hospitals were overwhelmed by patients whose ailments doctors could not explain. The end of the plague prompted an economic revival, with France following Britain into an industrial revolution. But as anyone who has read “Les Misérables” knows, the pandemic also contributed to another sort of revolution. The city’s poor, hit hardest by the disease, fulminated against the rich, who had fled to their country homes to avoid contagion. France saw political instability for years afterwards.

Today, even as covid-19 rages across poorer countries, the rich world is on the threshold of a post-pandemic boom. As vaccinations reduce hospitalisations and deaths from the virus, governments are lifting stay-at-home orders and loosening rules on social mixing. Many forecasters reckon that America’s economy will grow by around 7% this year, roughly five percentage points faster than the pre-pandemic trend of just over 2%. Other countries are also in for unusually fast growth (see chart 1).

The Economist’s analysis of GDP data for the G7 economies back to 1820 suggests that such a synchronised acceleration relative to trend is rare. It has not happened since the post-war boom of the 1950s.The situation is so unfamiliar that economists are turning to history to get a sense of what to expect. The record suggests that, following periods of massive non-financial disruption such as wars and pandemics, GDP does tend to bounce back. But it offers three further lessons. First, while people are keen to get out and spend, uncertainty lingers for some time. Second, the pandemic encourages people and businesses to try new ways of doing things, upending the structure of the economy. Third, as the example of “Les Misérables” shows, political upheaval often follows, with unpredictable economic consequences. headtopics.com

Take consumer spending first. Evidence from earlier pandemics suggests that during the acute phase people behave as they have during the past year of covid-19: accumulating savings as spending opportunities vanish and it becomes risky to go outside. In the first half of the 1870s, during an outbreak of smallpox, Britain’s household-saving rate doubled. Japan’s saving rate more than doubled during the first world war. In 1919-20, as the Spanish flu raged, Americans stashed away more cash than in any subsequent year until the second world war. When that war hit, savings rose again, with households accumulating additional balances in 1941-45 worth some 40% of GDP.

History also offers a guide to what people do once life gets back to normal. Spending rises, prompting employment to recover, but there is not much evidence of bacchanalian excess. The popular notion that people celebrated the end of the Black Death by “wild fornication” and “hysterical gaiety”, as some historians suppose, is (probably) apocryphal. The 1920s were far from roaring, at least at first. On New Year’s Eve 1920, after the threat of Spanish flu had decisively passed, “Broadway and Times Square looked more like the old days”, according to one study, though America nonetheless felt like “a sick and tired nation”. A recent paper by Goldman Sachs, a bank, estimates that in 1946-49 American consumers spent only about 20% of their excess savings. That extra spending certainly pushed the post-war boom along, though the government’s monthly “business situation” reports in the late 1940s were nonetheless filled with worry of an impending slowdown (and indeed the economy went into recession in 1948-49). Beer consumption actually fell in those years. Cautious behaviour from consumers may be one reason why there is little historical evidence of pandemic-induced surges in inflation (see chart 2).

The second big lesson from post-pandemic booms relates to the “supply side” of the economy—how and where goods and services are produced. Though, in aggregate, people appear to be less keen on frivolous fun following a pandemic, some may be more willing to try new ways of making money. Historians believe the Black Death made Europeans more adventurous. Piling on to a ship, and setting sail for new lands, seemed less risky when so many people were already dying at home. “Apollo’s Arrow”, a recent book by Nicholas Christakis of Yale University, shows that the Spanish flu pandemic gave way to “increased expressions of risk-taking”. Indeed a study for America’s National Bureau of Economic Research, published in 1948, found that the number of startups boomed from 1919. Today new business formation is once again surging across the rich world, as entrepreneurs seek to fill gaps in the market.

Other economists have drawn a link between pandemics and another change to the supply side of the economy: the use of labour-saving technology. Bosses may want to limit the spread of disease, and robots do not fall ill. A paper by researchers at the IMF looks at a number of recent outbreaks of diseases, including Ebola and SARS, and finds that “pandemic events accelerate robot adoption, especially when the health impact is severe and is associated with a significant economic downturn.” The 1920s were also an era of rapid automation in America, especially in telephone operation, one of the most common jobs for young American women in the early 1900s. Others have drawn a link between the Black Death and Johannes Gutenberg’s printing press. There is as yet little hard evidence of a surge in automation because of covid-19, though anecdotes abound of robots springing up. headtopics.com

Whether automation deprives people of jobs, however, is another matter. And some research suggests that workers in fact do better in the aftermath of pandemics. A paper published last year by the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco finds that real wages tend to rise. In some cases this is through a macabre mechanism: the disease culls workers, leaving survivors in a stronger bargaining position.

In other cases, however, rising wages are the product of political changes—the third big lesson of historical boom periods. When people have suffered in large numbers, attitudes may shift towards workers. That seems to be happening in this pandemic: policymakers across the world are relatively less interested in reducing public debt or warding off inflation than they are in getting unemployment down. A new paper from three academics at the London School of Economics also finds that covid-19 has made people across Europe more averse to inequality.

Read more: The Economist »



2
J'aime

Aucun commentaire

Vous devez être connecté pour laisser un commentaire. Connectez-vous.

Ose proposer une actualité